Marshall School of Business, USC
Business Field Project
at
Health Net, Inc. Investment Department
Hedging the volatility of Claim Expenses using Weather Future
Contracts
by
co written by
Emin Gabrielyan, PhD
Table
of Contents
Influenza Like Illnesses (ILI) and
Temperature Correlation
ILI as a Function of Temperature
Price probability density
transformation
Neutral (right) price of Futures
Probability density function of
insured costs and futures with right prices
Finding the optimal strike price and
volume of futures
The
purpose of the paper is to identify the correlation between weather temperature
patterns and Health Net, Inc. operation expenses and propose cost hedging
strategy using weather future contracts. The strategy is meant to decrease the
volatility of Company’s claim expenses throughout the year.
Observation
of historical data indicates that flu related illnesses consistently start from
November and last until May of each year.
The following chart shows 2008 to 2009 flu trend in
As you
can see the flu season picks during the coldest months of the year, December to
March. The following chart shows the daily average weather temperature trend in
The table
bellow shows the number of Health Net’s provider claim receipts for
|
Jul-08 |
Aug-08 |
Sep-08 |
Oct-08 |
Nov-08 |
Dec-08 |
Jan-08 |
Feb-08 |
Mar-08 |
Apr-08 |
May-08 |
Jun-08 |
Receipts |
429,160 |
438,524 |
403,605 |
442,639 |
391,065 |
408,075 |
428,135 |
444,627 |
466,394 |
453,089 |
434,268 |
424,140 |
Membership |
1,296,915 |
1,292,110 |
1,290,667 |
1,286,349 |
1,282,481 |
1,281,007 |
1,331,490 |
1,318,908 |
1,313,263 |
1,304,342 |
1,306,500 |
1,303,301 |
Receipts per Member |
33.09% |
33.94% |
31.27% |
34.41% |
30.49% |
31.86% |
32.15% |
33.71% |
35.51% |
34.74% |
33.24% |
32.54% |
This
analysis indicates that the number of receipts per member picks not in January-February, the coldest
months of the year with the most flu related illnesses but in March. This
perfectly correlates to the assumption of increased operating costs for managed
health care companies during flu season. There is a lag time between a doctor
visit and a claim submitted to the health insurance company by a provider. This
lag time averages at a little above one month.
The regression analysis of
SUMMARY
OUTPUT |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Regression
Statistics |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Multiple
R |
0.6960837 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.4845325 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Adjusted
|
0.4807142 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Standard
Error |
0.7963725 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Observations |
137 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
ANOVA |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
df |
SS |
MS |
F |
Significance
F |
|
|
|
Regression |
1 |
80.479981 |
80.479981 |
126.89817 |
3.661E-21 |
|
|
|
Residual |
135 |
85.618237 |
0.6342092 |
|
|
|
|
|
Total |
136 |
166.09822 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Coefficients |
Standard
Error |
t
Stat |
P-value |
Lower
95% |
Upper
95% |
Lower
95.0% |
Upper
95.0% |
Intercept |
10.434298 |
0.7731665 |
13.495539 |
8.282E-27 |
8.9052135 |
11.963383 |
8.9052135 |
11.963383 |
|
-0.1398187 |
0.0124119 |
-11.264909 |
3.661E-21 |
-0.1643656 |
-0.1152718 |
-0.1643656 |
-0.1152718 |
Weather
Futures are traded in Chicago Mercantile Exchange (CME). The contracts are on
the daily cumulative Heating Degree Days (HDD) and Cooling Degree Days (CDD)
for a month observed at a weather station.
HDD=max
(0,65-A) and CDD=max (0,A-65)
Where: A
is the average of daily minimum and maximum temperatures. One Future contract
is on $100 times the cumulative HDD or CDD for one full month. The historical
temperature average provided in the Table 2 is measured in
1906-2008 averages in |
Jul |
Aug |
Sep |
Oct |
Nov |
Dec |
Jan |
Feb |
Mar |
Apr |
May |
Jun |
Average Max |
81.94 |
82.55 |
81.33 |
77.23 |
72.87 |
67.29 |
66.03 |
66.93 |
68.52 |
70.57 |
72.65 |
76.63 |
Average Min |
62.55 |
63.19 |
61.90 |
58.35 |
53.30 |
49.23 |
48.19 |
49.38 |
51.03 |
53.13 |
55.97 |
59.20 |
Average Temperature |
72.24 |
72.87 |
71.62 |
67.79 |
63.08 |
58.26 |
57.11 |
58.16 |
59.77 |
61.85 |
64.31 |
67.92 |
HDD |
0.40 |
0.00 |
2.90 |
34.00 |
108.80 |
226.30 |
259.60 |
216.90 |
188.90 |
132.00 |
75.30 |
19.00 |
CDD |
217.60 |
239.60 |
195.40 |
110.90 |
44.70 |
11.10 |
8.40 |
11.40 |
18.90 |
30.60 |
46.50 |
98.50 |
For
Example, if we purchased one HDD future contract for January at a strike price
of 200 and if the average temperature held our pay off would have been (259.60-200)*$100=$5,960.
Historical average of daily HDD ranges from 0 to 9 and for month 0 to 270. However, HDD can reach as high as 750 in coldest parts of the world. Bellow is the temperature chart and a chart of deviation of my HDD calculation and WRCC HDD calculation based on historical daily average temperatures from1906 to 2008.
Incremental
percentage of
Similarly
ILI incremental as a function of HDD is mirrored image of
The purpose of the project is to hedge the flu season
Our
objective is to find futures' optimal strike price and volume to hedge the
enterprise expenses against volatility. For this purpose we introduce the
volatility cost of enterprise. On the other hand we shall introduce the profit
margin of the issuer of futures. In our model the average amount of
We
assume that the default debt cost (debtc) is equal to $300’000 (the
default price applicable for all scenarios where expenses end up at the average
of $12 mil). The multiplication factor (debtk) is a parameter changing
from 1.5 to 5. For instance if this factor is 2, it means that if the
enterprise ends up with an expense of $15.2 mil (i.e. one σ away
from the µ), it will cost extra $600’000 to the company (e.g. due to
short-term debt interests).
In this section we analyze
transformations of a probability density of an operation cost, caused by
purchases of futures (issued on the same level of the cost). We assume two free
variables in the purchasing of futures, the strike price and the quantity of
futures. We assume that all futures are purchased with the same strike price.
When the operation cost exceeds the strike price, the futures cover the given
percentage of the operation cost excess.
That percentage depends on the amount of futures purchased. It can vary from 0%
to 100% (underinsurance) or can be more than 100% (over-insurance). The choice
of the quantity of purchased futures determines the insurance ratio.
The
probability density of the hedged price is computed as follows:
Where:
c is the cost of
purchased futures
a is the strike price
k is the insurance ratio
(1 corresponds to 100%)
Obviously:
The following animation shows how the probability curve of price changes
when the ratio of insurance changes from 10% to 250%. The strike price is the
same in all samples. The cost of futures is computed with a very simplified
empiric formula (it is sufficient for this demonstration). As expected, this
animation shows that the more you increase the insurance ratio toward 100%, the
narrower the volatility of your prices becomes. We also see that the price,
when over insured, never exceeds the strike price plus the cost of insurance.
Animation link:
http://switzernet.com/people/aram-gabrielyan/public/090817-hedging-cost-with-futures/
Let
us have an operation price probability, a subject to normal Gaussian
distribution (see normal distribution):
The
following chart shows such distribution, where the mean value is equal to
$4’000 and the variance is equal to $1’000:
We
seek to compute the ‘right’ price of futures (issued for our operation cost) as
a function of the strike price a. Such futures pay-off each additional
$1 of operation cost exceeding the selected strike price a.
The
statistical ‘margin-less’ cost of such futures must be equal to:
The
cost computed in such a way contains neither a security nor a beneficiary
margin of the issuer of futures.
Using
the above formula the joined Excel file computes the cost of futures
straight-forwardly by summing refund claims weighted by their probabilities.
For each price exceeding the strike price, the formula takes the difference
between the price and the strike-price, multiplies it by the probability of the
price, and adds all of them together. The final sum is multiplied by the
distance between the sample points on the x axis.
Our
objective is to find the analytical formula of the price of futures (and if not
analytical then one using well known functions, such as the error function).
Due
to the symmetric bell shape of the normal distribution:
Therefore:
CDF
is the cumulative distribution function [see normal distribution].
It represents the probability that the price will fall below x (its
argument).
[xls]
Considering
the product rule (see derivative):
We
can write that:
Therefore:
CDF
can be expressed via error function as follows (see normal distribution):
ERF
Excel function is implemented so no approximations or simulations is needed.
It is known that (see list of integrals):
Taking
into account the chain rule (see derivative):
The
CDF integral is computed as follows:
The
‘margin-less’ price of futures can be therefore expressed as follows:
The
following animation shows the price of futures as a function of the strike
price where the variance, i.e. the volatility, changes from $100 to $6500 over
the time. The mean value is always the same and is equal to $4000:
Animation link:
http://switzernet.com/people/aram-gabrielyan/public/090819-neutral-price-vs-Black-Scholes/
In Price probability density transformation [090817 ii] we developed the probability density
function of operation costs insured by futures. This density is also a function
of selected strike price and of insurance ratio k (representing the pay-off
ratio of cost units exceeding the strike price a, or otherwise the amount of
purchased futures). In the document we assumed the cost of futures c as an input
parameter. No formula was provided for computing the cost of futures.
In
Neutral (right)
price of Futures [090819 ii] we developed a formula for computing the ‘right’ cost of
futures for a given strike price a. Under term ‘right’ or ‘neutral’ we
understand the price, such futures would cost to an insurance company taking
into account the volatility of the cost. This shall be an integral of excess of
operation prices exceeding the strike price a weighted by the normal
distribution of the operation price (see normal distribution).
The
formula of futures price that we developed in [090819 ii], is fully analytical, with the exception of error function
ERF implemented in Excel (see error function).
Because
the price of futures is right, if computed as follows:
The
following must hold for all a and k
In
order to validate both of our formulas, we use an Excel model. The mean of our
operation cost at $12 mil and the variance is $3.2 mil. For a two-dimensional
set of parameters, (a) strike prices varying from $4 mil to $20 mil and (b) the
insurance ratios varying from 10% to 200%, we compute ‘right’ prices of futures
using our formula . The blow chart
shows this function for the two dimensional set of input parameters:
Sub-sequentially,
based on the right price, we compute probability density values with our
formula by loading
results into an array with prices ranging from $0 to $23’500’000.
The
following animation shows that the choice of a and k can change
the shape of price distribution significantly:
Animation link:
http://switzernet.com/people/aram-gabrielyan/public/090819-average-of-hedged-cost/
By
having, for each shape (dictated by a pair of strike price a and
insurance ratio k) of the probability density array we compute the mean
of the insured operation cost:
Irrespectively
how wildly the probability density shape is changed (by the choice of two
parameters of futures), the Excel simulation shows that the computed mean of
insured operation costs is always equal to the mean of the uninsured costs,
i.e. to µ (with exceptions of
precision errors). This suggests no hidden costs in prices of futures.
The
results of this simulation validate our two formulas for calculation of the
‘right’ price of futures and
subsequent calculation of the insured costs' probability density
.
In
our model we deal with future contracts that can pay-off a portion of
enterprise expenses exceeding a pre-selected strike price. The choice of the
pay-off portion (of the excess with respect to the strike price) is made by the
choice of the amount of purchased futures. This fraction can be less than, more
than, or equal to 1. This model is applicable to a more general case, where
instead of futures issued directly on the enterprise expenses, the futures are
issued on another underlying instrument highly correlated to the enterprise
expenses. HDD future contracts are a good example of such instruments.
Our
objective is to find the optimal strike price and volume of futures, purchased
for hedging the enterprise expenses against volatility (see Cost of Debt section.)
In
[090817 ii] we developed price probability density transformation
achieved by the purchase of futures. In [090819a ii] we developed a formula for computing the neutrally or
right price of futures. In [090819b ii] we showed that the mean of insured expenses does not
change, if the futures are bought at neutrally right prices. This means that if
the market price of futures is always right, we are definitely interested in
purchasing futures all the time, even if the volatility cost is low. Futures
are narrowing the probability density of expenses and are therefore minimizing
the volatility related debt costs.
However
the pleasure of having a future based insurance shall often have a market cost
exceeding its neutrally right price [090819a ii]. The difference between the market price of futures and
the right price computed by our formulas [090819a ii] is precisely the cost of this pleasure. This cost must be
counterbalanced with savings achieved on the volatility side. The margin added
on the right price of futures is represented in percentages. We analyze a range
from 0.5% to 90%.
In
the following chart we assume that the default debt cost (debtc) is
equal to $300’000 (the default price applicable for all scenarios where
expenses end up at the average of $12 mil). The multiplication factor (debtk)
is a parameter changing from 1.5 to 5. For instance if this factor is 2, it
means that if the enterprise ends up with an expense of $15.2 mil (i.e. one
variance away from the mean), it will cost extra $600’000 to the company (e.g.
due to short-term debt interests) (see Cost of Debt
section.)
The
surface shown in the animation below represents the overall cost (the
volatility debt cost together with the profit margins paid to issuers of
futures) as a function of the strike price (in the range from $4 mil to $20
mil) and the insurance ratio (in the range from 10% to 200%). The animation
shows the changes in the shape when changing the issuer's profit margin
(fairness) and the debt cost factor (dependence). For each frame (i.e. for each
pair of fairness of futures and dependence of enterprise from the volatility),
the text data panel shows the best recommended strike price and insurance
ratio.
This
animation demonstrates the concave shaped form of the surface for all pairs of
fairness and dependence showing that
there is always an optimal choice to make depending on the market prices of
futures and the extra cost of the volatility of the enterprise expenses.
Animation link:
http://switzernet.com/people/aram-gabrielyan/public/090820-best-strike/
Hedging the volatility of Claim Expenses using Weather Future Contracts (this document):
http://switzernet.com/people/aram-gabrielyan/public/090823-hedging-with-weather-futures/
http://unappel.ch/people/aram-gabrielyan/public/090823-hedging-with-weather-futures/
This document in Web [htm], [doc] and printable formats [pdf], [doc], [docx]
Finding the optimal strike price and volume of futures for hedging against the volatility of enterprise expenses:
http://switzernet.com/people/aram-gabrielyan/public/090820-best-strike/
http://unappel.ch/people/aram-gabrielyan/public/090820-best-strike/
Validation of the formula of the ‘right’ price of futures and of the function of the insured price’s probability density:
http://switzernet.com/people/aram-gabrielyan/public/090819-average-of-hedged-cost/
http://unappel.ch/people/aram-gabrielyan/public/090819-average-of-hedged-cost/
Right price of futures as a function of the strike price:
http://switzernet.com/people/aram-gabrielyan/public/090819-neutral-price-vs-Black-Scholes/
http://unappel.ch/people/aram-gabrielyan/public/090819-neutral-price-vs-Black-Scholes/
Probability density of a hedged price:
http://unappel.ch/people/aram-gabrielyan/public/090817-hedging-cost-with-futures/
http://switzernet.com/people/aram-gabrielyan/public/090817-hedging-cost-with-futures/
* * *